French President Emmanuel Macron
proposes a semi-proportional system for France: a 20% “proportional share"
for Parliamentary elections. (Also, the number of parliamentarians will be
reduced by 25% to 30%.) He made this announcement April 25, after a “great
national debate” that began January 14, 2019. He had stated “The system of representation
is the bedrock of our Republic, but it must be improved because many do not
feel represented after the votes. What is the right level of proportional
representation in parliamentary elections for a fairer say to be given to all
political perspectives?”
In his presidential campaign he had promised "a dose of proportionality." This share of 20% had been
debated for the past year: would it be the 15% proposed last summer, 20%, or
25%?
Based on last summer’s discussions, it seems this “dose of proportionality” (PR-lite) is non-compensatory, based on national vote shares, with no threshold.
Based on last summer’s discussions, it seems this “dose of proportionality” (PR-lite) is non-compensatory, based on national vote shares, with no threshold.
The
history of proportional representation in France
France had always, before the First World War, used
either a block vote system, with several deputies for each “department,” or the
two-round system in single-member districts. During
1907-1914 support for PR built up, and a bill was passed in 1912 but vetoed by
the Senate. PR became an election issue in the 1914 election, and a majority of
the newly elected deputies had promised PR. The War started three months later.
Based on the electoral
mandate, the Senate yielded in June 1919. France’s first PR election was in
1919, and again in 1924.
The 1919 election was moderately
proportional in the 89 “Departments” for the 613 seats, an average of 7 seats
per district, with a minimum of 3. It was an open-list system, but you have as
many votes as deputies to be elected. Any candidate winning over 50% of the
voters was elected, and then PR by list was used. Parties ran altogether 324
lists, 3 or 4 per department: one socialist, and 2 or 3 or 4 others of various
groups of the centre and right; the right won a majority.
The 1924 election for 581
seats was won by the centre-left and left. It had the same system except that
departments with more than 6 deputies were split, and the Socialists and Communists had separate lists. However, in July 1926 a
financial crisis brought the right and centre-right to power, and they
changed the voting system in 1927. For the 1928 election France
reverted to their previous two-round system in single-member districts.
The Fourth Republic used PR for
the 1945 Consultative Assembly and from 1946 to 1951 for the National Assembly.
In 1945 it had closed lists. In 1946 the lists were closed unless at least half
the votes for the list were personal votes, in which case the list order was
applied as well as the personal votes. Districts ranged from three to nine
seats in 1945, three to eleven MPs in 1946. The 1946 districts in France had an
average of 5.3 MPs, 553 seats in 105 districts. The calculation was highest
average.
From 1951 to 1958 this
continued, except for a mechanism to favour parties other than the two biggest
(Gaullists and Communists). This allowed the coalition called “Third Force,” centrists
and centre-left originally led by the Socialist Party, the government since 1947, to
remain in power until 1958. The lists had the opportunity to ally with each
other in each district through an "apparentement". If the sum of the
votes obtained by the “apparented” lists corresponds to at least half of the
votes cast, these lists take all the seats allocated in the district. Also, in
two districts the rule of the largest remainder was used, a gerrymander against
the Communists in those two districts. Again, the lists were closed unless
personal votes are at least half the votes for the list, but now in that case
the list order was not applied, ranking was by only the personal votes.
In 1951, even with the “apparentement,”
the three “Third Force” parties won only 47% of the seats, squeezed between the
Gaullists 19% and the Communists 16%, leaving them increasingly dependent on
the other 15% won by the centre-right alliance. As these same leaders shuffled
and reshuffled their alliances for five years, this left French politics as a
shifting series of coalitions.
In the 1956 election the Communists
became the largest party with 25% of the seats. Some apparentements continued
between some centre-left, centre and centre-right lists, but accomplished little
except to limit the number of seats won by the new right-wing Poujadists. With
the six parties of the centre-left and centre-right badly divided over Algerian
policy, governments foundered until the 1958 military coup in Algeria led to
the return of Charles de Gaulle. By then, proportional representation had few
defenders and was abolished. De Gaulle brought back the winner-take-all system in two rounds.
For the 1985 election the
Socialist President Franรงois
Mitterand brought back PR, the system of proportional representation by
district. There was a 5% threshold, and closed lists. It had 570 MPs from
France, in 100 districts, an average of 5.7 MPs per district. The calculation was
again by highest average. In 1986 the conservatives reversed it.
Note: with only about 6 MPs
per district, this was a moderate form of PR, as indeed France has always used.
Opponents were not concerned about small extremist parties. They wanted to get
centrists and rightists into a big centre-right tent.
However, France understands PR
very well. Municipal governments and regional assemblies used proportional or
semi-proportional systems from 1947 to 1959, and again since 1982. European
Parliament elections, starting in 1989, are by PR.